Skip to main content

Health and life insurance as an alternative to malpractice tort law

Abstract

Background

Tort law has legitimate social purposes of deterrence, punishment and compensation, but medical tort law does none of these well. Tort law could be counterproductive in medicine, encouraging costly defensive practices that harm some patients, restricting access to care in some settings and discouraging innovation.

Discussion

Patients might be better served by purchasing combined health and life insurance policies and waiving their right to pursue malpractice claims. The combined policy should encourage the insurer to profit by inexpensively delaying policyholders' deaths. A health and life insurer would attempt to minimize mortal risks to policyholders from any cause, including medical mistakes and could therefore pursue systematic quality improvement efforts. If policyholders trust the insurer to seek, develop and reward genuinely effective care; identify, deter and remediate poor care; and compensate survivors through the no-fault process of paying life insurance benefits, then tort law is largely redundant and the right to sue may be waived. If expensive defensive medicine can be avoided, that savings alone could pay for fairly large life insurance policies.

Summary

Insurers are maligned largely because of their logical response to incentives that are misaligned with the interests of patients and physicians in the United States. Patient, provider and insurer incentives could be realigned by combining health and life insurance, allowing the insurer to use its considerable information access and analytic power to improve patient care. This arrangement would address the social goals of malpractice torts, so that policyholders could rationally waive their right to sue.

Peer Review reports

Background

Health care is a risky endeavor [1]. The industry has made some progress in improving safety following the Institute of Medicine report, "To err is human", but malpractice reforms to reduce blame and improve accountability have lagged consistently [2].

Malpractice tort law has three theoretically important purposes [3]. First, threats of malpractice suits should deter physicians from practicing beyond their expertise. Second, malpractice suits should punish those who practice low quality care. Third, malpractice awards are a process for compensating patients injured by low quality care. One might hope that by achieving these purposes, malpractice tort law would further the broader goals of better health care and outcomes.

Unfortunately, current malpractice tort law does none of these tasks very well. Malpractice suits are not sensitive: real injuries are common but seldom pursued and only a small fraction result in paid claims [4–10]. This is in part due to the difficulty of detecting negligence: patients may file suits just to learn whether negligence occurred [11]. Malpractice suits are not specific: many invalid claims are paid and may be paid in proportion to the injury suffered rather than the quality of care delivered [9]. A recent review described a "good correlation" between the strength of evidence for medical negligence and physicians' probability of losing a malpractice trial [12], but correlation is not accuracy. Physicians lost 10-20% of cases with weak evidence of negligence, while patients won only 50% of cases with strong evidence of negligence. Malpractice claim history is predictive of future malpractice claims [13, 14], but such claims largely reflect poor interpersonal skills [15–17]. High quality training may reduce risk [18] but in some cases the most knowledgeable physicians have been more likely to be sued than their peers [19]. In one specialty, board certified physicians experienced fewer state disciplinary actions than non-certified physicians, but equal numbers of malpractice claims [20]. It is therefore not at all clear that malpractice tort law compensates victims of medical mistakes or identifies clinically incompetent physicians.

Furthermore, adverse events are about equally frequent in malpractice tort systems and less expensive "no fault" systems for compensating disabled patients [21, 22]. These observations suggest that malpractice tort law does no better at preventing mistakes or compensating victims than alternative systems.

Malpractice tort law has important unintended effects. Believing that they face a capricious threat of losing time, money and reputation, many physicians practice expensive defensive medicine [23–27]. The annual cost of defensive medicine in the United States is substantial, possibly as high as $100 billion [26, 28–30]. Defensive medicine can be harmful as well [25, 31]. For instance, all x-ray images entail at least a small risk of causing cancer [32]. Collectively, defensive radiographic imaging could pose a non-trivial public health problem [33]. False positive test results can initiate an injurious and expensive cascade of events. Still worse, high risk of malpractice suits may discourage technically qualified physicians from offering services that would benefit patients [25, 34–37]. The unintended consequences of malpractice torts could cause harm without offsetting benefits to society.

Constructive change has been hard to achieve. A small survey reported that physicians do not believe that lawyers have the moral authority to guide medical practice and would prefer physician-led quality control measures [38]. Deliberate quality control efforts can reduce harmful variation in practice, decrease adverse events and prevent litigation [39–41]. In a particularly dramatic example, application of quality control methods to the very complex problem of ventilator management for adult respiratory distress syndrome (ARDS) patients improved their survival from less than 10% to more than 40%. The improvement occurred before the investigators learned anything new about adjusting ventilator settings for ARDS patients [40]. This is evidence-based medicine at its best: not an artificially constrained trial, but an exhaustive effort by dedicated clinicians informed by comprehensive observational data collection and analysis to make sense of the consequences of their actions for a wide range of patients. It was possible, at least in principle, for any hospital to deliver comparable care to ARDS patients, but only one group of researchers perceived a need to standardize a complex and variable health care process as a prerequisite for their studies. Physician-led quality control can be very effective, but is rare and usually addresses less complex problems than ARDS.

No-fault compensation for poor medical outcomes and independent arbitration are less confrontational and potentially less expensive complements to malpractice tort law. Apology laws have been advocated as another means of indirectly reducing medical error, ideally in combination with no-fault compensation [42]. However, United States citizens cannot be forced to accept these processes in place of malpractice torts, because the seventh amendment to the US Constitution guarantees trials by jury when sums of $20 or more are in question. The right can be abridged by legislative acts only if the justice system agrees that a compelling argument favors the abridgement. Therefore, US citizens would have to be persuaded by some compelling argument to waive this right. Guaranteed compensation would help, but it is not clear how strongly this would encourage general improvements in the quality of medical outcomes unless health care insurers provide the guarantee.

Physicians often call for caps on malpractice awards [43]. This may reduce malpractice insurance costs and even state health care costs [44], although a recent analysis suggests no effect [45]. Some argue that caps are not nearly ambitious enough reforms and call for a new system of medical justice [46, 47], but sweeping reform is unlikely [43]. Other countries restrain malpractice activity by avoiding jury trials and contingency fees, restricting pretrial discovery and forcing the loser to pay the legal costs of the winner [48]. Caps and stronger reforms leave physician reputations at risk and the prospect of defending a suit remains daunting. The path of least resistance still may be to charge a patient, or an insurance pool, for a test that suggests that the physician left no stone unturned in the effort to serve the patient, even if the test has negative expected value and drains the insurance pool. Physicians facing any serious threat of malpractice suits are likely to feel similar pressure. Furthermore, these reforms do not provide direct incentives to improve patient care.

The Obama administration has rejected major tort reform as a component of federal health care reform. However, the administration has acknowledged that state experiments in tort reform could be instructive. The following discussion describes a possible insurance reform that could be implemented by states and how it might obviate medical tort law.

Discussion

Health and Life Insurance

There is only one group in the US health care industry that routinely collects enough data to monitor, compare and reward quality care. That group is not patients, physicians, pharmaceutical companies, public health agencies, hospitals, academics, or politicians. It is insurers. That every other group views insurers with deep and largely justified distrust is a tragic result of misaligned incentives: insurers increase profits by collecting premiums and not paying claims. Insurers must maintain a sufficiently respectable reputation to collect premiums from policyholders and must abide by contracts. A tense relationship with health care providers and patients is not surprising.

Combining health and life insurance in a single long-term policy should realign insurers' incentives and lend credibility to many insurer decisions [49, 50]. Policyholders would pay insurance premiums for both health and life insurance, while the insurer would reimburse medical care. When a policyholder died, the insurer would pay a death benefit to the policyholder's designated beneficiaries. Neither the insurer nor the policyholder could casually terminate the relationship. Policies that endure a minimum of 5 years would give insurers the opportunity to reap some short-term reward for influencing health.

Policyholders could use a combination of term and permanent life insurance to convey longevity preferences to the insurer. Term policies convey interest in avoiding fatal accidents, while permanent policies (variable and whole life insurance) imply interest in longevity. Ideally, a basic policy would be established relatively early in life, with the expectation that policyholders could negotiate amendments to the life insurance policy. As in any viable insurance program, policyholders would need to initiate coverage while healthy, or pay a premium to purchase coverage with a pre-existing condition.

The insurer could profit in two ways. First, it could keep aggregate spending on health care below the sum of collections of health insurance premiums. Second, it could earn more from invested life insurance premiums than it pays in life insurance benefits if it can increase average life expectancy, whether by preventing accidental deaths, increasing longevity, or both. If the insurer finds inexpensive ways to heal, maintain health and extend longevity, the policyholders benefit. Conversely, neglect and other health care mistakes are likely to manifest as losses on life insurance and increased long-term health costs. This should create a tense resource allocation decision. It needs to be shared, as much as possible, between suffering patients, harried physicians and well-informed, highly analytical insurers.

The insurer could take a very broad perspective regarding policyholders' health. Profitable activities could be as diverse as lobbying against anti-health interests, subsidizing healthy behaviors and reducing environmental risks. A health and life insurer should have an especially strong interest in the quality of medical care provided to policyholders. In many situations, the insurer could profit twice from directing policyholders to high quality care, once if the care succeeds in avoiding complications and disability that would create additional medical expenses and again if the care reduces mortal risk. Conversely, the insurer would pay twice for failure to obtain high quality care for the average policyholder. Therefore, the insurer could reimburse health care systems or even individual physicians based on the quality of the care they deliver.

Health and life insurers would have incentives to develop nuanced measures of the quality of care. Pay for performance initiatives typically use simple quality measures and may not change outcomes appreciably [51–56]. Simple quality measures, such as the fraction of diabetics whose hemoglobin A1c is below 7%, could encourage physicians to avoid or drop patients who do not meet the precise goal [57]. Simple quality measures also are likely to focus too much attention on marginal improvements that are not cost-effective with respect to health. For instance, a provider might have greater financial incentive to help five patients reduce their hemoglobin A1c from 7.1% to 7% than to invest effort in a difficult patient at 10%. In contrast, a health and life insurer should reward providers who manage to reduce challenging diabetics' hemoglobin A1c from 10% to 8%, because this reduces long-term risk substantially. This is an example of a medical version of economists' "law of diminishing returns" and likely applies to every numeric goal in medicine: the greatest risk reduction occurs as extreme values move toward a more normal goal, not when the goal is reached.

The health and life insurer also should maintain a healthy skepticism regarding extrapolated quality measures. For instance, anticoagulation to prevent blood clots is clearly valuable for many orthopedic surgery patients, but involves serious trade-offs and may not change short-term mortality among internal medicine inpatients [58]. Nevertheless, thromboprophylaxis is a common quality measure in both orthopedic and medical settings. A health and life insurer could reasonably and credibly reject thromboprophylaxis as a quality measure in medical settings, or develop a nuanced policy identifying subsets of medical inpatients who do benefit from thromboprophylaxis. A similar analysis could address the recent controversy regarding breast cancer screening among women under age 50 [59]. Interestingly, the insurer might reject or endorse routine early mammography based largely on policyholders' life insurance purchases.

These calculations suggest a reimbursement strategy that could be called "fee for expected benefit" [60]. A health and life insurer has an opportunity to divide the profits accrued by delaying deaths, avoiding complications and reducing unnecessary care among providers and patients. The policyholder's life insurance purchases, the diseases suffered and providers' skill determine the treatment strategy and the profit that could be shared. The insurer could tailor these reimbursements to reinforce the careful teamwork required to achieve significant benefits for patients [61]. Most importantly, a health and life insurer paying fees for expected benefits should gain the credibility needed to reduce or deny payment for useless or overly expensive treatments - if the service could save costs by reducing disability and death at a reasonable price, the insurer would pay for it.

Replacing Malpractice Suits

Health and life insurers would provide nearly all of the social benefits of tort law. The insurer could reward and penalize providers based on average patient outcomes. Observing poorly executed care, the insurer should demand quality improvements or end reimbursements. The insurer increases profits when it employs providers who have, or can learn, the skills required to manage high-risk cases. In under-served settings, insurers might encourage and guide expansion of primary care physicians' services. If insurers are competing for high quality services for policyholders, then the insurers should spend to retain the most skilled physicians. This should encourage physicians to hone their skills, stay current with evolving treatment, monitor their patients' outcomes and seek assistance when needed rather than risk mishaps that could threaten personal income. These penalties and rewards should address the social goals of confining clinicians' scope of practice to areas of competence and punishing low quality care.

Health and life insurers will always pay a price for injurious medical mistakes, whether or not mistakes come to the attention of patients, their families, or the judicial system. The insurance beneficiaries of patients who die from medical mistakes are always compensated. Young patients who die can leave fairly large settlements to their survivors by purchasing inexpensive term life policies. The life insurance benefit therefore establishes a no-fault process for compensating the survivors of patients who suffer fatal medical mistakes. After non-fatal mistakes, the insurer often will pay a new stream of health care expenses. A health and life insurance policy also could include disability insurance, comprising at least a provision to suspend premium payments in the event of disability. This would further encourage insurers to reduce non-fatal mistakes. The insurer will consistently compensate victims of low quality care, or their estates, thus addressing the third goal of tort law.

Policyholders may be willing to waive their right to jury trials if they trust health and life insurers to identify and then discourage or remediate poor quality care, encourage and refine high quality care and stand by them or compensate their survivors after adverse events. Optional independent adverse event review panels could provide arbitration and root cause analysis services.

If the health insurance premium is held constant, the savings from avoiding defensive medicine could subsidize the life insurance policy. If defensive medicine actually costs $100 billion per year in a nation of 300 million persons and could be eliminated by replacing malpractice threats with more constructive quality improvement processes, then the implied annual per capita savings could exceed $300. For healthy middle-age male non-smokers, that savings is enough to pay the entire premium for $100,000 of term life insurance. Alternatively, over 15 years the savings could pay for about $8,000 of whole life insurance. While the costs of defensive medicine are not likely to be distributed evenly across the population, savings on this scale should be available to large insurers.

If a health and life insurer can curtail unnecessary care, a much larger amount of money could be available to subsidize life insurance purchases. According to the World Health Organization Statistical Information System (WHOSIS), among western nations in 2006, the United States spent $3,100 to $4,200 more per capita on health care than Australia, Canada, France, Germany, New Zealand, Sweden, or the United Kingdom, yet US citizens faced a 109/1,000 risk of death between ages 15 and 60, 20% to 50% higher than the other nations [62]. At a state or national level, most of this money should be transferable from health care to life insurance without reducing life expectancy. Pockets of high-quality, low-cost health care in the USA convincingly demonstrate that the goal is practical [63]; what remains to be discovered is a means of consistently motivating such success. A health and life insurer in the USA should find many opportunities to profit by reducing health expenses and extending lives.

Physician role

Health and life insurance should not reduce the practice of medicine to algorithmic care, although there is some danger of that outcome. Rather, these insurers will need to work with expert clinicians to understand as many predictable nuances of diagnosis and treatment as possible. Insurers should prize clinicians who are discriminating history takers, expert physical examiners, selective testers, accurate diagnosticians, and clever patient managers when these skills reduce costs or improve outcomes. Insurers should strive to develop and support these clinicians, as only insurers could.

Summary

Combining health and life insurance could reconcile the health interests of patients with the financial interests of one of the best-informed but least trusted industries in health care. Negotiations between these parties could provide an objective foundation for setting the prices of many medical goods and services. One of the potential benefits is that properly implemented health and life insurance should consistently promote the social goals that malpractice lawsuits promote so inconsistently, with direct and indirect cost savings. The savings from avoiding malpractice suits and defensive medical practice could substantially offset the cost of life insurance for policyholders.

References

  1. Committee on Quality of Health Care in America, Institute of Medicine: To Err Is Human: Building a Safer Health System. 2000, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press

    Google Scholar 

  2. Wachter RM: Patient Safety At Ten: Unmistakable Progress, Troubling Gaps. Health Aff (Millwood). 2009

    Google Scholar 

  3. Dobbs D, Keeton R, Owen D: Prosser and Keeton on Torts. 1984, St. Paul, MN: West Publishing Co, 5

    Google Scholar 

  4. Brennan TA, Localio AR, Leape LL, Laird NM, Peterson L, Hiatt HH, Barnes BA: Identification of adverse events occurring during hospitalization. A cross-sectional study of litigation, quality assurance, and medical records at two teaching hospitals. Ann Intern Med. 1990, 112 (3): 221-226.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  5. Leape LL, Brennan TA, Laird N, Lawthers AG, Localio AR, Barnes BA, Hebert L, Newhouse JP, Weiler PC, Hiatt H: The nature of adverse events in hospitalized patients. Results of the Harvard Medical Practice Study II. N Engl J Med. 1991, 324 (6): 377-384.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  6. Brennan TA, Leape LL, Laird NM, Hebert L, Localio AR, Lawthers AG, Newhouse JP, Weiler PC, Hiatt HH: Incidence of adverse events and negligence in hospitalized patients. Results of the Harvard Medical Practice Study I [see comments]. N Engl J Med. 1991, 324 (6): 370-376.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  7. Localio AR, Lawthers AG, Brennan TA, Laird NM, Hebert LE, Peterson LM, Newhouse JP, Weiler PC, Hiatt HH: Relation between malpractice claims and adverse events due to negligence: Results of the Harvard Medical Practice Study III. N Engl J Med. 1991, 325: 245-251.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  8. Wenner WJ, Lambert R: Delayed diagnosis of infantile meningitis. Medical and legal outcomes. Qual Assur Util Rev. 1991, 6 (3): 82-84.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  9. Brennan TA, Sox CM, Burstin HR: Relation between negligent adverse events and the outcomes of medical-malpractice litigation. N Engl J Med. 1996, 335 (26): 1963-1967. 10.1056/NEJM199612263352606.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  10. Studdert DM, Thomas EJ, Burstin HR, Zbar BI, Orav EJ, Brennan TA: Negligent care and malpractice claiming behavior in Utah and Colorado. Med Care. 2000, 38 (3): 250-260. 10.1097/00005650-200003000-00002.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  11. Farber HS, White MJ: Medical malpractice: an empirical examination of the litigation process. Rand J Econ. 1991, 22 (2): 199-217. 10.2307/2601017.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  12. Peters PG: Twenty years of evidence on the outcomes of malpractice claims. Clin Orthop Relat Res. 2009, 467 (2): 352-357. 10.1007/s11999-008-0631-7.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Bovbjerg RR, Petronis KR: The relationship between physicians' malpractice claims history and later claims. Does the past predict the future?. JAMA. 1994, 272 (18): 1421-1426. 10.1001/jama.272.18.1421.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. Weycker DA, Jensen GA: Medical malpractice among physicians: who will be sued and who will pay?. Health Care Manag Sci. 2000, 3 (4): 269-277. 10.1023/A:1019014028914.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Hickson GB, Clayton EW, Entman SS, Miller CS, Githens PB, Whetten-Goldstein K, Sloan FA: Obstetricians' prior malpractice experience and patients' satisfaction with care. JAMA. 1994, 272 (20): 1583-1587. 10.1001/jama.272.20.1583.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  16. Tamblyn R, Abrahamowicz M, Dauphinee D, Wenghofer E, Jacques A, Klass D, Smee S, Blackmore D, Winslade N, Girard N, et al: Physician scores on a national clinical skills examination as predictors of complaints to medical regulatory authorities. JAMA. 2007, 298 (9): 993-1001. 10.1001/jama.298.9.993.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  17. Hickson GB, Entman SS: Physician practice behavior and litigation risk: evidence and opportunity. Clin Obstet Gynecol. 2008, 51 (4): 688-699. 10.1097/GRF.0b013e3181899c2c.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  18. Waters TM, Lefevre FV, Budetti PP: Medical school attended as a predictor of medical malpractice claims. Qual Saf Health Care. 2003, 12 (5): 330-336. 10.1136/qhc.12.5.330.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  19. Ely JW, Dawson JD, Young PR, Doebbeling BN, Goerdt CJ, Elder NC, Olick RS: Malpractice claims against family physicians are the best doctors sued more?. J Fam Pract. 1999, 48 (1): 23-30.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  20. Kocher MS, Dichtel L, Kasser JR, Gebhardt MC, Katz JN: Orthopedic board certification and physician performance: an analysis of medical malpractice, hospital disciplinary action, and state medical board disciplinary action rates. Am J Orthop. 2008, 37 (2): 73-75.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  21. Davis P, Lay-Yee R, Briant R, Scott A: Preventable in-hospital medical injury under the "no fault" system in New Zealand. Qual Saf Health Care. 2003, 12 (4): 251-256. 10.1136/qhc.12.4.251.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  22. Pukk-Harenstam K, Ask J, Brommels M, Thor J, Penaloza RV, Gaffney FA: Analysis of 23 364 patient-generated, physician-reviewed malpractice claims from a non-tort, blame-free, national patient insurance system: lessons learned from Sweden. Qual Saf Health Care. 2008, 17 (4): 259-263.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  23. Localio AR, Lawthers AG, Bengtson JM, Hebert LE, Weaver SL, Brennan TA, Landis JR: Relationship between malpractice claims and cesarean delivery. JAMA. 1993, 269 (3): 366-373. 10.1001/jama.269.3.366.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  24. Katz DA, Williams GC, Brown RL, Aufderheide TP, Bogner M, Rahko PS, Selker HP: Emergency physicians' fear of malpractice in evaluating patients with possible acute cardiac ischemia. Ann Emerg Med. 2005, 46 (6): 525-533. 10.1016/j.annemergmed.2005.04.016.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  25. Studdert DM, Mello MM, Sage WM, DesRoches CM, Peugh J, Zapert K, Brennan TA: Defensive medicine among high-risk specialist physicians in a volatile malpractice environment. JAMA. 2005, 293 (21): 2609-2617. 10.1001/jama.293.21.2609.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  26. Baicker K, Fisher ES, Chandra A: Malpractice liability costs and the practice of medicine in the Medicare program. Health Aff (Millwood). 2007, 26 (3): 841-852. 10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Brown HS: Lawsuit activity, defensive medicine, and small area variation: the case of Cesarean sections revisited. Health Econ Policy Law. 2007, 2 (Pt 3): 285-296. 10.1017/S1744133107004136.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  28. Rubin RJ, Mendelson DN: How much does defensive medicine cost?. J Am Health Policy. 1994, 4 (4): 7-15.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  29. Medical malpractice litigation raises health-care cost, reduces access, and lowers quality of care. J Med Pract Manage. 2004, 20 (1): 44-51.

  30. Massachussetts Medical Society: Investigation of Defensive Medicine in Massachusetts. 2008, [http://www.massmed.org/AM/Template.cfm?Section=Home6&CONTENTID=27797&TEMPLATE=/CM/ContentDisplay.cfm]

    Google Scholar 

  31. Fisher ES, Welch HG: Avoiding the unintended consequences of growth in medical care: how might more be worse?. JAMA. 1999, 281 (5): 446-453. 10.1001/jama.281.5.446.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Smith-Bindman R, Lipson J, Marcus R, Kim K-P, Mahesh M, Gould R, Berrington de Gonzalez A, Miglioretti DL: Radiation Dose Associated With Common Computed Tomography Examinations and the Associated Lifetime Attributable Risk of Cancer. Arch Intern Med. 2009, 169 (22): 2078-2086. 10.1001/archinternmed.2009.427.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  33. Berrington de González A, Mahesh M, Kim K-P, Bhargavan M, Lewis R, Mettler F, Land C: Projected Cancer Risks From Computed Tomographic Scans Performed in the United States in 2007. Arch Intern Med. 2009, 169 (22): 2071-2077. 10.1001/archinternmed.2009.440.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  34. Amon E, Winn HN: Review of the professional medical liability insurance crisis: lessons from Missouri. Am J Obstet Gynecol. 2004, 190 (6): 1534-1538. 10.1016/j.ajog.2004.03.057. discussion 1538-1540

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Mello MM, Studdert DM, DesRoches CM, Peugh J, Zapert K, Brennan TA, Sage WM: Effects of a malpractice crisis on specialist supply and patient access to care. Ann Surg. 2005, 242 (5): 621-628. 10.1097/01.sla.0000182957.54783.9a.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  36. Kessler DP, Sage WM, Becker DJ: Impact of malpractice reforms on the supply of physician services. JAMA. 2005, 293 (21): 2618-2625. 10.1001/jama.293.21.2618.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  37. Elmore JG, Taplin SH, Barlow WE, Cutter GR, D'Orsi CJ, Hendrick RE, Abraham LA, Fosse JS, Carney PA: Does litigation influence medical practice? The influence of community radiologists' medical malpractice perceptions and experience on screening mammography. Radiology. 2005, 236 (1): 37-46. 10.1148/radiol.2361040512.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  38. Hupert N, Lawthers AG, Brennan TA, Peterson LM: Processing the tort deterrent signal: a qualitative study. Soc Sci Med. 1996, 43 (1): 1-11. 10.1016/0277-9536(95)00314-2.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  39. Morris AH: Computerized protocols and bedside decision support. Crit Care Clin. 1999, 15 (3): 523-545, vi. 10.1016/S0749-0704(05)70069-5.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  40. James BC, Hammond ME: The challenge of variation in medical practice. Archives of Pathol Lab Med. 2000, 124 (7): 1001-1003.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  41. Clark SL, Belfort MA, Byrum SL, Meyers JA, Perlin JB: Improved outcomes, fewer cesarean deliveries, and reduced litigation: results of a new paradigm in patient safety. Am J Obstet Gynecol. 2008, 199 (2): 105 e101-107. 10.1016/j.ajog.2008.02.031.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Dresser R: The limits of apology laws. Hastings Cent Rep. 2008, 38 (3): 6-7. 10.1353/hcr.0.0015.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  43. Studdert DM, Mello MM, Brennan TA: Medical malpractice. N Engl J Med. 2004, 350 (3): 283-292. 10.1056/NEJMhpr035470.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  44. Hellinger FJ, Encinosa WE: The impact of state laws limiting malpractice damage awards on health care expenditures. Am J Public Health. 2006, 96 (8): 1375-1381. 10.2105/AJPH.2005.077883.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  45. Sloan FA, Shadle JH: Is there empirical evidence for "Defensive Medicine"? A reassessment. J Health Econ. 2009, 28 (2): 481-491. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.12.006.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  46. Howard PK: Is the medical justice system broken?. Obstet Gynecol. 2003, 102 (3): 446-449. 10.1016/S0029-7844(03)00619-7.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  47. Howard PK: Health Reform Requires Lawsuit Reform. Wall Street Journal. 2009, 15.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Epstein RA: How Other Countries Judge Malpractice. Wall Street Journal. 2009, 15.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Sumner W, Nease R, Foreman S: Aligning patient and insurer incentives. Med Decis Making. 1995, 15 (4): 420.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Sumner W: The Integrated Health & Life Insurer: Harmonization of Patient's, Provider's Insurer's and Public Health Perspectives. White Papers in Length and Quality of Life. 2002, Longer Life Foundation

    Google Scholar 

  51. Ryan AM, Burgess JF, Tompkins CP, Wallack SS: The relationship between Medicare's process of care quality measures and mortality. Inquiry. 2009, 46 (3): 274-290.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  52. McDonald R, White J, Marmor TR: Paying for performance in primary medical care: learning about and learning from "success" and "failure" in England and California. J Health Polit Policy Law. 2009, 34 (5): 747-776. 10.1215/03616878-2009-024.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  53. Tanenbaum SJ: Pay for performance in medicare: evidentiary irony and the politics of value. J Health Polit Policy Law. 2009, 34 (5): 717-746. 10.1215/03616878-2009-023.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  54. Ryan AM: Effects of the Premier Hospital Quality Incentive Demonstration on Medicare patient mortality and cost. Health Serv Res. 2009, 44 (3): 821-842. 10.1111/j.1475-6773.2009.00956.x.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  55. Glickman SW, Ou FS, DeLong ER, Roe MT, Lytle BL, Mulgund J, Rumsfeld JS, Gibler WB, Ohman EM, Schulman KA, et al: Pay for performance, quality of care, and outcomes in acute myocardial infarction. JAMA. 2007, 297 (21): 2373-2380. 10.1001/jama.297.21.2373.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  56. Mehrotra A, Damberg CL, Sorbero ME, Teleki SS: Pay for performance in the hospital setting: what is the state of the evidence?. Am J Med Qual. 2009, 24 (1): 19-28. 10.1177/1062860608326634.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  57. Damberg CL, Raube K, Teleki SS, Dela Cruz E: Taking stock of pay-for-performance: a candid assessment from the front lines. Health Aff (Millwood). 2009, 28 (2): 517-525. 10.1377/hlthaff.28.2.517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Dentali F, Douketis JD, Gianni M, Lim W, Crowther MA: Meta-analysis: anticoagulant prophylaxis to prevent symptomatic venous thromboembolism in hospitalized medical patients. Ann Intern Med. 2007, 146 (4): 278-288.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  59. Screening for breast cancer: U.S. Preventive Services Task Force recommendation statement. Ann Intern Med. 2009, 151 (10): 716-726. W-236

  60. Sumner W: Four proposals for market-based health care system reform. Arch Fam Med. 1994, 3 (8): 660-664. 10.1001/archfami.3.8.660.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  61. Wynia MK: The risks of rewards in health care: how pay-for-performance could threaten, or bolster, medical professionalism. J Gen Intern Med. 2009, 24 (7): 884-887. 10.1007/s11606-009-0984-y.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  62. WHOSIS: WHO Statistical Information System. 2009, World Health Organization, [http://www.who.int/whosis/en/]

  63. Fisher E: How do they do that? What we know now: a brief overview. How Do They Do That? Low-Cost, High-Quality Health Care in America. Washington, DC. 2009

    Google Scholar 

Pre-publication history

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Rebecca Dresser, J.D., Professor of Law at Washington University in St. Louis, for reviewing the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Walton Sumner II.

Additional information

Competing interests

The author declares that he has no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

This article is published under license to BioMed Central Ltd. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sumner, W. Health and life insurance as an alternative to malpractice tort law. BMC Health Serv Res 10, 150 (2010). https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/1472-6963-10-150

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/1472-6963-10-150

Keywords